The
basic research question for Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) is "How firms
decide their boundaries when the firms are views as a nexus of contracts?
". The
main idea is that transactions should be organized to safeguard the contingencies
of the exchange. The process to safeguard the exchange has cost (transaction
cost). There are three
organizational forms of transaction cost economics: market, hybrid and hierarchy.
Hierarchy has advantage over market, because it more efficient in governing
complex transactions. (Williamson, 1998).
Transaction
cost economics have three premises, which render a contract incomplete. The incomplete
contract leads to opportunism, which a potential cost for the contractors.
First, Human
cognition has limitations. Therefore, individuals cannot foresee the future
contingencies and potential opportunism and plan well. Second, two contracting
parties cannot develop a completely common language of the state of the world
and possible actions. Third, the third-party, who enforces the contract, can
have a hard time in understanding the contract interpreted by both of the
parties.
(North,1990; Williamson, 1985)
Practically, transaction cost can be manipulated by
measuring three different constructs. First, higher asset specificity means
higher transaction cost. Asset specificity refers to
the transferability of assets to alternative uses (Williamson, 1985). Williamson
(1985) identify three types of asset specificity: 1) site specificity 2)
physical specificity 3) human asset specificity. Site specificity: the
situation whereby successive production stages that are immobile in nature are
located close to one another. It reduces inventory and transportation costs and
can lower the costs of coordinating activities (Dyer, 1996). Physical asset
specificity: transaction-specific capital investments (e.g. customized
machinery) that tailor processes to particular exchange partners. Physical
asset specificity has been found to allow for product differentiation and may
improve quality by increasing product integrity or fit (Clark and Fujimoto,
1991). Human asset specificity refers to transaction-specific know-how accumulated
by contractors
through long-standing relationships. The more specialized a
resources becomes, the lower its value is in alternative uses. Therefore, it is
harder to switch partners. The contingent value of a specialized resource
exposes its owner to a greater risk of opportunism than does a general resource
( Klein et al.,1978). Firms, who develop a specific assets will face the hold-up
problem, where the
suppliers can extract extra rents from the consumers with opportunism, because
the specified assets are of little value out of given context. Second,
appropriability refers to
the contracting hazards when the valuable intellectual property of the firms is
exposed to expropriation (Gualti & Singh, 1998; Oxley, 1997;Pisano,1990).
When firms engage in a contract in the market, they may have to exchange their
proprietary information and technology. The partner firms who get the
expropriate valuable technology can compete with the original firms to extract
the rent from the technology. Contracts cannot fully prevent the moral hazard
(Shapiro & Varian, 1999). Therefore, firms would want to internalize their
transactions. Third, when
the outcomes are hard to observe, the contract hazard is high
(Holmstrom, 1979).
There are four main critics for transaction cost economies.
First, it ignores the
role of differential capabilities in structuring economic organization
(Richardson 1972). This point is further developed by Resource-based Theory
and Knowledge-based Theory.
Second, it excessively
focused on the assumption of opportunism. For instance, Ghoshal and Moran
(1996) claimed that opportunism is not exogenous. Once the situational sources
of opportunism (rather than the dispositional source) are factored in,
Williamson’s prescriptions for mitigating the hazards of opportunism within
organizations are likely to enhance it. Therefore, Williamson’s approach
becomes a “self-fulfilling prophecy” and it thus “bad for practice”.
Third, it views organization
as instrument controlling pathological behavior, but neglects the institutional
role of organizations which is embedded in the social networks (Granovetter
1985). In those critics, firms are often portrayed in rosy terms as
“mini-societies” (Freeland 2002) that provide “identity” (Kogut and Zander
1996), “higher-order organizing principles” (Kogut and Zander 1992), and trust
relations (Ghoshal and Moran 1996) that, purportedly, “atomistic” markets
cannot provide. Firms exist because and to the extent that they not only allow
managers to lower the cost and to increase the effectiveness of economic
activity, but also create and sustain a context in which collaborative
entrepreneurial behavior can flourish. Research, developing in
this vein, has incorporate institution theories and population ecology. Hughes
et al. (1997) study the contracting practices in the Welsh National Health
Services (NHS) are subject to both efficiency and political influences. Study
about strategic alliances between firms show that trust and relational governance
partly mitigate the transaction costs (Gualti and Singh, 1998). Park and Russo
(1996) find that the dissolution of joint venture is influenced both by
organizational age and efficiency.
Fourth, the uncertainty is not theorized well. Weber, L.,
& Mayer, K. (2014) discuss that different contractors’ cognitive framing is
the source of uncertainty in contracting. Different governance forms are chosen
to allow different degree of communication to align the cognitive frameworks.
By Kate Jue Wang
By Kate Jue Wang
References:
Ghoshal,
S., & Moran, P. (1996). Bad for Practice : a Critique O F the Transaction
Cost Theory. Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 13–47.
Macher,
J. T., & Richman, B. D. (2008). Transaction Cost Economics: An Assessment
of Empirical Research in the Social Sciences. Business and Politics, 10(1),
1–65.
Moran,
P., & Ghoshal, S. (1996). Theories of Economic Organization : the case for
realism and Balance. The Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 58–72.
Willamson,
O. E. (1996). Economic Organization: The Case for Candor. Academy of Management
Review, 21(1), 48–57. Retrieved from
Williamson,
O. E. (1979). Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual
relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233.
Williamson,
O. E. (1991). Comparative Economic The Analysis Organization : Analysis of Discrete
Structural Alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2), 269–296.
Williamson,
O. E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic
Management Journal, 20(12), 1087–1108
Weber,
L., & Mayer, K. (2014). Transaction cost economics and the cognitive
perspective: Investigating the sources and governance of interpretive
uncertainty. Academy of Management Review, 39(3), 344–363.
No comments:
Post a Comment